Agrowth instead of anti- and pro-growth: less
polarization, more support for sustainability/climate policies
First online: 1 October 2018
Jeroen
C.J.M. van den Bergh
Jeroen
van den Bergh is ICREA Professor at the Institute of Environmental Science and
Technology of Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (2007–present), and full
Professor of Environmental & Resource Economics at VU University Amsterdam
(1997–present). His research is on the interface of environmental economics,
energy-climate studies and innovation research. He is Editor-in-Chief of the journal Environmental Innovation and
Societal Transitions. He received the Royal/Shell Prize 2002 for
Sustainability Research, IEC’s Sant Jordi Environmental Prize 2011 and an ERC
Advanced Grant. His most recent book is Human
Evolution Beyond Biology and Culture: Evolutionary Social, Environmental and
Policy Sciences (Cambridge
University Press, October 2018).
–––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––
DOI: 10.3197/jps.2018.3.1.53
Licensing: This article is Open Access (CC BY 4.0).
How to Cite:
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. 2016. 'Agrowth Instead of Anti-and Pro-Growth: Less Polarization, More Support for Sustainability/Climate Policies'. The Journal of Population and Sustainability 3(1): 53–73.
https://doi.org/10.3197/jps.2018.3.1.53
–––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––
An agrowth strategy, defined as being agnostic and indifferent
about GDP growth, is proposed as an alternative to unconditional anti- and
pro-growth strategies. It is argued that such a strategy can contribute to
reducing scientific and political polarization in the long-standing debate on
growth versus the environment. Hence, it can broaden urgently needed support
for serious sustainability and climate policies. The exposition includes a
novel graphical illustration, a summary of recent surveys of citizens and
scientists regarding support for an agrowth position, and a discussion of
implications for population growth and policies.
Acknowledgements: I am grateful to the editor, David
Samways, for careful reading and insightful comments.
1. Growth fixation as a barrier to
sustainability policies
Humanity
faces serious sustainability challenges but has been incapable so far of
implementing sufficiently strict policies that guarantee a sustainable course
of the economy. One important reason is that voters and politicians – fueled by
pessimistic environmental science studies – fear that serious policies will
hamper economic growth. Whether this will be the case or not is of no
relevance. What matters is the psychology behind it. If people cannot be
convinced that policies will not harm growth then such policies will not
receive majority support. Of course, one could respond by claiming that green
growth is possible, even though the evidence for this is weak. In fact, the
uncertainty surrounding this issue is immense and it is impossible to provide
definite proof of whether or not green growth is feasible. What we know for
sure is that current growth is not sustainable and that for a while, during a
transition phase, it will remain unsustainable. One way out of this dilemma is
to refrain from trying to convince voters and politicians that green growth is
possible. In fact, economists have been unsuccessful in persuading both groups,
otherwise good sustainability policies would have already been implemented. I
will propose here that we should become agnostic and indifferent about GDP
growth, i.e. adopt an agrowth position (van den Bergh, 2011). One
reason is that the GDP is not a good indicator of happiness or social welfare.
Another reason applies specifically to rich countries where for some time
increases in average income growth have not contributed to significant
increases in social welfare.
Climate
change illustrates the need for an ideological shift to agrowth (van den Bergh,
2017). The challenges posed by climate change and policies to tackle it have
revived the growth debate. Modern economies and lifestyles are highly dependent
on burning fossil fuels, generating CO2 emissions
responsible for global warming. If per capita GDP increases by 1.5% annually,
to realize the 2°C goal (supported by IPCC and the Paris Climate Agreement),
carbon intensity or emissions per unit of GDP should decrease by some 80% by
2050, which comes down to a 4.4% average annual improvement (Antal and van den
Bergh, 2016). Even if economic growth would come to a halt – i.e. in the case
of zero growth – still an impressive 67% intensity reduction, or 2.9% on
average per year, will be required. Since these reduction rates should be net
of all energy rebound (Sorrell, 2007) and carbon leakage effects (Felder and
Rutherford, 1993), they are merely lower bounds. Under serious climate policy
the rate of economic growth is thus likely to drop for some time, possibly
until we have reached a zero-carbon economy. Such a consequence will induce
fear for and opposition to associated climate policies in many advocates of
green growth. An agrowth strategy, on the other hand, will facilitate the
acceptance of these policies as it will free us from the unnecessary,
welfare-obstructing growth paradigm. This will result in removing false
trade-offs between GDP growth and other goals arising from the constraint of
always, at any time and under any conditions, having to achieve GDP growth.
2. We should abandon GDP but are
unable
A
large majority of economists, journalists and politicians, irrespective of
their political affiliation, express themselves uncritically about GDP and fail
to distinguish it clearly from (social) welfare. Nevertheless, a growing group
of economists, including many Nobel laureates, have explicitly accepted the
shortcomings of GDP (summarized in Table 1). Early critics included eminent
economists such as Kuznets (1941), Galbraith (1958) and Samuelson (1961). Later
influential voices are Mishan (1967), Nordhaus and Tobin (1972), Hueting
(1974), Hirsch (1976), Sen (1976), Scitovsky (1976), Daly (1977), Tinbergen and
Hueting (1992), and Arrow et al. (1995); more recent contributions come from
Frank (2004), Kahneman et al. (2004), Victor (2008) and Jackson (2009).
In
line with this, empirical research on happiness suggests that in most Western
(OECD) countries the increase in prosperity or happiness stagnated somewhere in
the period between 1950 and 1970 or even reversed to negative trend, despite
the steady growth in GDP per capita (Layard, 2005). This is supported by
empirical studies of alternative indicators of social welfare, such as the ISEW
(Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare) (Daly and Cobb, 1989). Moreover,
psychological research has found that individuals quickly become accustomed or
adapt to new conditions, including income increases, and as a result welfare
increases fall short of ex ante expectations (Easterlin, 1974).
Unfortunately,
the majority of economists are less critical and accept or even overtly support
the false idea that that GDP growth always means progress. They should realize
that both microeconomic and macroeconomic theories tend to formulate societal
goals in terms of social welfare not GDP or its change. In the standard
utility-maximizing behavioral model of microeconomics, income co-determines,
with prices, the budget constraint, rather than being a proxy for utility.
Likewise, in macroeconomics, growth theory is dominated by models of optimal
economic growth in which the guiding criterion is (intertemporal) social
welfare rather than an aggregate GDP type of income measure.
Table 1. Main shortcomings of
GDP as a proxy of social welfare
General |
Specific |
GDP use does not satisfy basic principles of good
bookkeeping |
– GDP does not
distinguish clearly between costs and benefits. – It does not
correct for changes in (economic and environment) stocks. – It does not
account for external (or social=private+external) costs. – It is an estimate
of the costs rather than benefits of market activities in a country. |
Using GDP (growth) as a proxy of social welfare (progress)
is inconsistent with the general welfare focus in microeconomics and
macroeconomics |
– Optimal growth theory
employs social welfare rather than GDP/income type of criteria. – In microeconomics,
income is part of the budget constraint, not a proxy of utility. – If income is not a
robust measure of welfare at the individual or micro-level, then aggregation
of individual incomes into GDP cannot result in a robust indicator of social
welfare. |
GDP does not capture stylized facts of empirical research
on subjective well-being (happiness) |
– Modern income
growth increases material consumption at the cost of basic needs like
serenity, clean air, and direct access to nature; the latter are, however,
not captured by GDP. – Somewhere between
1960 and the present, the increase in welfare stagnated or even reversed into
a negative trend in most Western countries, despite the steady pace of GDP
growth. – Individuals may
adapt or get used to changed circumstances, including a higher income; thus
well-being may temporarily change in response but then return to its baseline
level. |
GDP does not capture income inequality, relative income,
and status-seeking in consumption |
– GDP per capita
emphasizes average income, and neglects the income distribution, even though
this affects opportunities for personal development and well-being. – GDP does not
capture that individuals or families with low incomes benefit relatively more
from an income rise, because of the diminishing marginal utility of income. – Welfare is
relative or context-dependent, characterized by comparing oneself with
others, rivalry via “positional or status goods”. – As GDP omits
relative income aspects of welfare, it tends to overestimate social welfare
and progress. – Rises in relative
income and welfare come down to a zero-sum game: one individual loses what
another one gains; GDP cannot account for this. |
GDP neglects the informal economy, its share in the whole
economy, and its change |
– In general, GDP
just covers activities and transactions that have a market price and neglects
informal transactions between people that occur outside formal markets. – Actual GDP growth
sometimes reflects a transfer of existing informal activities (unpaid labor)
to the formal market; so the benefits were already enjoyed but the market costs
were not yet part of GDP. – This holds for
both developed and developing countries, and for such informal activities as
subsistence agriculture, voluntary work, household work, and child care. – The GDP can,
therefore, not serve as a measure to judge the welfare impact of fundamental
changes that involve a transition from informal to a formal activities |
GDP does not capture environmental externalities, damage
to ecosystems, and depletion of renewable and non-renewable natural resources |
– The presence of
externalities means that market prices do not reflect total social
(=private+external) costs, making them unreliable signals. GDP is, however,
calculated using these prices. – If air, water, or
a natural area are being polluted, any damage does not enter GDP, but when
pollution is being cleaned up this contributes to GDP. – Capital
depreciation associated with environmental changes (fish stocks, forests,
biodiversity) and depletion of resource supplies (fossil energy, metal ores)
is missing from the GDP calculation. As a result, GDP suggests we are richer
than we really are. |
Note: This table is reproduced from
van den Bergh (2017) and summarizes the survey in van den Bergh (2009).
So if this is all true, why do
so many influential people get nervous when there is little GDP growth? This
paradox (van den Bergh, 2009) can be explained by all of us constantly
receiving the message, through news media and in education, that economic
growth is imperative. Moreover, the response to low GDP growth from
politicians, economists, financial markets and international organizations like
the OECD (e.g., 2011), the World Bank (e.g., 2012), and the IMF is consistently
negative. They all signal that GDP growth is a sine qua non for our society. An
important additional reason is the widespread belief that GDP growth is a
necessary condition for economic stability and full employment. Empirical
evidence for this view is weak though, indicating that the relationship between
GDP and employment is not constant (Saget, 2000). Broadly accepted insights
about long-run equilibrium employment suggest that it depends more on search
time (jobs and employees); structural mismatches between education and work;
the difference between gross and net income; and the gap between income and
unemployment benefits (Pissarides, 2000). Moreover, the causality of growth and
employment is easily confused as more employment can increase GDP rather than
the reverse. In this respect, the “productivity trap”, coined by Jackson and
Victor (2011), is relevant. It denotes that growth compensates for potential
unemployment resulting from technological innovation driving labor productivity
improvements. This is possible as a higher labor productivity translates into
higher incomes, allowing for additional purchasing power to balance the larger
production capacity associated with productivity increases. This is, in a
nutshell, the fundamental mechanism driving economic growth. Incidentally, by
shifting taxes from income to environmental externalities one could redirect
technological change from improving the productivity of labor to that of energy
and material inputs to production. As a result, it would be easier to realize
full employment and environmental goals simultaneously.
3. Agrowth elaborated
An agrowth position
or strategy comes down to being agnostic about, i.e. ignoring, the GDP (per
capita) indicator in public debates and policymaking. It means we will be
indifferent, neutral or “agnostic” about the desirability of GDP growth, an
idea first proposed in van den Bergh (2011). The motivation is the insight that
unconditional growth implies an unnecessary and avoidable constraint on the
search for human welfare and progress. By definition, such a constraint hampers
the achievement of good public policies and decisions in any area, whether
social, health, labor, equity, education, environment or climate. This is
graphically illustrated by Figure 1 in van den Bergh (2017). One should note
that an agrowth position opposes unconditional GDP growth, also known as the
growth paradigm, but not growth per se.
Under an agrowth strategy,
periods of high, low, zero and even negative growth could alternate with one
another, as long as environmentally sustainability and progress in terms of
welfare were guaranteed. We would no longer give priority to average income
over welfare, or assume growth would be necessary or sufficient for progress.
While progress might sometimes coincide with growth, nobody would really care.
With regard to environmental pressures, an agrowth strategy would allow for
selective decline and selective growth of distinct economic and industrial
sectors which would not necessarily translate into aggregate GDP growth.
By ignoring GDP information, we
would in some periods be capable to give up potential GDP growth for a better
environment, less unemployment, more income equality, more leisure or better
health care. As a result, welfare-enhancing policy would be given priority over
GDP growth-enhancing policy. This would contribute to social-political acceptability
of public policies focusing on solving urgent and socially important problems
that are likely to reduce social welfare. Such an approach is consistent with
the advice by Nobel laureate Daniel Kahneman et al. (2004) to focus the
attention of public policy on minimizing unhappiness. Clear examples are
avoiding dangerous climate change, minimizing structurally high unemployment,
and reducing extreme inequality and poverty. Whether these policies would work
out well in terms of growth of GDP (per capita) would no longer be an issue.
Another advantage of an agrowth
strategy is that it increases economic stability and reduces the likelihood of
economic crises. The reason is that it weakens positive feedback in the economy
which contributes to business cycles and crises. As argued in Antal and van den
Bergh (2013), the current economic system is self-amplifying because a majority
of the connections between important economic system variables take the form of
positive feedbacks, while a minority of such connections takes the form of
negative feedbacks. A positive feedback denotes that an output of a system
enters the same system as an input, which then reinforces the actual trend in
the output. This is irrespective of whether the trend is a decline or a growth
pattern. In other words, positive feedback can generate negative and positive
spirals. Expectation about, and predictions of, GDP growth can be characterized
as being pro-cyclical, in the sense that if it is widely believed that such
information has a significant influence on reality, then, through pessimistic
(or optimistic) reactions to negative (positive) growth expectations, these
beliefs become self-fulfilling. This sets in motion positive feedback
affecting, among others, consumer expenditures and savings, firm expenditures
and investments, which result in economic instability.
Positive feedback assures that,
as long as we are on the upward trend, there is optimism about the economy. If,
though, growth weakens and expectations are not met, pessimism about future GDP
growth starts to set in, potentially leading to a recession. Two common
solutions are offered by Keynesian and monetarist or new classical[1] schools of macroeconomics. The first
recommends stimulating aggregate demand by increasing public spending or
lowering taxes. The second proposes austerity and debt reduction to restore
confidence. These strategies, although polar opposites, share the goal of restoring
the upward economic spiral driven by positive feedback. And in environmental
terms, both put their full confidence in green growth. Instead, an agrowth
strategy tackles a fundamental positive feedback mechanism underlying economic
instability, namely the role of GDP information. By suggesting to ignore the
GDP indicator, it weakens positive feedback in the economy, resulting in a more
stable economy. This will discourage extremely high growth rates but also lower
the probability of recessions.
Antal and van den Bergh (2013)
discuss a long list of options to weaken other positive feedbacks and
strengthen or create negative feedbacks, with the aim to improve economic
stability. One recommendation is to replace the GDP by another indicator, such
as the Human Development Index, an income inequality measure (Gini index or
median income), or an ISEW-type of proxy of social welfare (Daly and Cobb,
1989). Another idea is to construct an index that is an average of a minimum,
medium and mean income, as it results in a monetary indicator that captures
income inequality well (van den Bergh, 2017a).
Empirical evidence suggests
that agrowth may count on reasonable support, which means it could depolarize
the debate on growth-versus-environment. Figure 1 depicts results from two
questionnaire surveys, among scientists and citizens. While green growth is the
most popular position, scientists express relatively more support for agrowth
and less for green growth than citizens. With more discussion of a recent and
new idea like agrowth one might expect support for it to increase.
Source: Drews and van den Bergh (2019). Data from Drews and van
den Bergh (2016 and 2017).
Figure 1. Scientists’ versus citizens’ preferences for a public
policy strategy regarding growth and the environment
4. Riskiness of pro- and anti-growth strategies
The historical debate on growth
versus the environment is often summarized as between optimists believing in
limitless growth and pessimists seeing environmental and natural resource
limits to growth. This opposition best defines the main policies and strategies
found: namely, striving for green growth by decoupling income and production
from environmental pressure versus an anti-growth approach taking the form of
stopping growth (zero-growth) for the sake of the environment. However, a more
subtle classification of viewpoints in the growth debate is possible, such as
the five perspectives identified by van den Bergh and de Mooij (1999): a
moralist, denying the relevance of further growth for individual and social
welfare, notably in rich countries; a pessimist, stressing environmental and
resource limits to growth; a technocrat, seeing markets and technological
progress as powerful mechanisms to relieve any existing limits; a sceptic,
assessing economic growth and environmental ruin as both unavoidable; and an
optimist, considering growth as a requirement for solving environmental
problems since it makes citizens more concerned about the environment.
Even though many economists and
international organizations express a strong belief in green growth, few
politicians demonstrate that they share this belief through their actual
decisions. Instead, they signal fear that serious climate policies will reduce
the rate of economic growth. This suggests that economists have not provided
sufficiently convincing evidence for the feasibility of green growth. This is
no surprise, as the future is uncertain, and we have not yet succeeded in
applying all the policy conditions that guarantee a sustainable economy, hence
we do not know if such an economy could steadily grow in GDP terms. Theory says
both outcomes are possible (Acemoglu et al., 2012). If green growth is not
feasible, however, any strong messages about its realization will create false
hopes. As a result, one will harm either the environment or economic stability.
Recently, a particular
expression of anti-growth has appeared: so-called “degrowth” has the explicit
aim of downscaling the economy to meet environmental goals (Schneider et al.,
2010; Kallis, 2011). It can be interpreted as complicating climate policy with
a quest for radical change. Degrowth is unlikely to be an effective strategy
for creating broad political support given that it focuses on variables with an
indirect link to emissions, instead of on the carbon content of growth, in
addition to its basic message that we need income and other sacrifices to save
the environment (Drews and Antal, 2016). Furthermore, as degrowth does not
follow a clear welfare approach and is not focused on sharply distinguishing
between low-carbon and high-carbon consumption, it runs the risk of destroying
too much welfare for the purpose of sustainability, without even guaranteeing
an effective, let alone a cost-effective, way of solving sustainability
problems. For instance, the degrowth proposal does not offer a clear framework
for satisfactorily balancing – from a welfare perspective – changes in inputs
(e.g., fuels), energy efficiency of technologies, composition of production and
consumption, and volume or scale of activities. Any physical or GDP degrowth
goal will then be arbitrary and debatable. Another shortcoming is that the term
“degrowth” is defined and used differently by distinct authors. One can identify
at least five interpretations (van den Bergh, 2011), namely as GDP decline,
less consumption (unclear how measured), a work-time reduction, a smaller
physical size of the economy, and a radical move away from “capitalism” and
markets. Such ambiguity does not contribute to productive societal or
scientific exchange. The proposal for degrowth is likely to contribute to
polarization, creating sharp differences between supporters and opponents of
degrowth. If we sell climate solutions as degrowth, then support for these is
likely to diminish rather than rise over time.
Instead, an agrowth strategy
can, because of its neutrality and indifference regarding GDP growth, bridge
pro-growth and anti-growth views and so reduce polarization. In fact, I have
many personal experiences with degrowth and green growth believers expressing
support for the agrowth position. To see why it can bridge the divide, one
should recognize that agrowth does not preclude GDP growth when it is feasible
and improves human welfare, and neither rejects GDP decline when an outcome of
good social or environmental policies. In view of this, an agrowth strategy has
the potential to create and amplify the political space for balancing distinct
components of social welfare, such as consumption, employment, environment,
leisure, health, and inequality. In particular, agrowth will make it easier to
sell serious climate policy to the public and politicians, much easier than
selling degrowth. In addition, by tempering preoccupation with continued GDP growth,
it will moderate panic that is common among economists, journalists and
politicians when GDP growth slows down. In other words, an agrowth strategy
contributes to economic stability.
Figures 2 and 3 graphically
illustrate that an agrowth strategy, i.e. indifference about where on the
horizontal axis (indicating the rate of GDP growth) the economy is positioned,
is robust against uncertainty about the relationship (curve 1 versus 2) between the GDP growth rate (horizontal axis) and the change in
other components of human welfare including environmental sustainability (ES)
(vertical axis). It is assumed here that environmentally desirable outcomes
require being positioned above the horizontal 0 (zero) line, meaning that no reductions in
environmental performance are accepted. Hence, a degrowth strategy strives to
be in (rectangular) area A,
a zero-growth strategy on the top (positive) part of vertical line h, a low growth strategy in (rectangular) area B, and a high-growth strategy in (rectangular) area C (where
growth is higher than rate g,
such as the often expressed desire of at least 2% growth). However, an agrowth
strategy does not exclude any of these areas.
Now, a pessimistic perspective
on the growth-vs-environment relationship is shown in Figure 2 through a
downward-sloped curve 1 that represents the upper bound to feasible
combinations of changes in GDP and ES,
while Figure 3 displays an optimistic perspective through an upward-sloped
curve 2.
Consider first Figure 2, where a green growth strategy aiming for growth beyond
the rate g is not wise as it will not achieve its aim of
ending up in area C.
The reason is illustrated by the red position above the constraint 1which represents an infeasible goal. If one strives for high
growth associated with it, the economy will end up in the blue point below the
constraint (following the arrow). In this case degrowth (area A) and low growth (area B)
strategies are feasible. On the other hand, in the case depicted in Figure 3, a
high growth strategy is feasible but a degrowth strategy not because while
environmental impacts get lower, it becomes increasing difficult to sustain
human welfare. Indeed, trying to be in area Afails
here as one will be forced to be below constraint 2, indicated by an arrow from the red goal to the blue realization.
Hence, unlike an agrowth strategy that is tolerant to any outcome (positive,
zero or negative GDP growth, or areas A, B and C), neither growth and degrowth strategies are robust or
precautionary in the face of uncertainty about the conflict between growth and
environmental sustainability (represented by uncertainty about whether curve 1 or 2 holds
true). For further discussion, see van den Bergh (2017).
In conclusion, both green
growth and degrowth lack credible empirical support and make debatable
assumptions. These limitations make either of them risky strategies in solving
environmental and climate change problems, as well as more generally in
realizing progress in terms of social welfare. We do not need to assume that
growth and environment are conflictive or compatible. Recognizing uncertainty
about the future and complexity of the economy warrants being precautionary –
making an agrowth strategy the better response.
Note: Search space for human progress spanned by relative changes
in GDP & ES in interval [t, t+1]; bold letters denote the rectangles separated by the vertical and
horizontal broken lines.
Figure 2. Growth strategy fails in case of conflict between growth
and environmental sustainability, while degrowth and agrowth strategies remain
within feasibility area indicated by area below brown curve 1.
Figure 3. Degrowth strategy
fails in case of no conflict between growth and environmental sustainability,
while agrowth and growth strategies remain within feasibility area indicated by
area below green curve 2.
5. Climate change and population growth
Climate change is also affected
by population growth, while income GDP growth affects both of them in different
directions with an uncertain net outcome, depending on the country and other
factors. On the one hand, before we have made a transition to low-carbon
technologies, economic growth will increase emissions directly. On the other
hand, increasing income goes along with a demographic transition in certain
parts of the developing world, leading birth rates to go down due to, among
other factors, a fall in infant mortality leading parents to recognise that
fewer births will meet their needs in old age, urbanization, improved education
of women and access to contraception (Chesnais, 1992). An agrowth position does
not deny the need for economic growth so a scenario where growth contributes to
demographic transitions in some countries (notably in sub-Saharan Africa) may
be an outcome. In rich countries with low or no population growth, however, low
economic growth is more likely as a transition scenario before a low-carbon
economy is achieved. For some middle-income countries with high birth rates the
trade-off is less clear beforehand and the net effect of economic growth on
emissions, taking population effects into account, may be either positive or
negative. An agrowth strategy is consistent with such a diversity of growth
strategies in different countries, notably poor and rich ones, unlike a green
growth position which requires high growth in all countries, denying national
diversity of potential and need for growth. Note that agrowth as a strategy
does not apply to population directly. Instead, population growth worldwide
needs to be stopped as soon as possible to avoid further overshooting of the
human economy, including with regard to global warming.
A recent account of the link
between climate and population and adequate policies is provided by Bongaarts
and O’Neill (2018). They argue against various misperceptions, such as that
population growth is under control and does not matter much for climate change,
and that population policies are ineffective and too controversial to succeed.
Possibly, the worst decision one can make in terms of climate-change
externalities is not to buy a product or service but to have a child (Harford,
1998; Wynes and Nicholas, 2017), unless during its life-time it will invent
some cheap zero-emission technology that will change the world. It implies
additional emissions over the entire lifetime of a child, decades into the
future. With a growing number of people on Earth, the carbon budget associated
with a safe climate is quickly exhausted. In view of this, some have proposed,
in addition to a tax on the carbon content of energy, goods and services,
so-called birth taxes (Kennedy, 1995). One argument why the decision of having
a child should be regulated or priced separately is that parents make this
decision while arguably only accounting for their own welfare effects and
neglecting any social or environmental costs generated by the child in the
future. Moreover parents may be insufficiently rational to perceive all private
costs of raising children until adulthood. In addition, the desired number of
children will be influenced by the culture and religion to which parents
belong. Parents will thus be unable to respond rationally or optimally to the
sum of private and social costs (as captured by the carbon tax), suggesting
that birth regulation is required as well to assure that climate goals are
reached. The magnitude of this is not insignificant: Bohn and Stuart (2015)
calculate that an optimal child tax equals 21.1% of a corrected per capita
income during the time span of a generation. They illustrate this for the USA,
noting that the relevant income measure was on average ± $48,000 per adult per
year during the study period, which translates into a child tax of about
$10,000 per year during a period of 30 years from birth on. Hence, over the 30
year period the undiscounted sum of annual taxes would amount to $300,000.
Implementation of such a policy would arguably also contribute to reducing
poverty in the next generation as a larger share of people would be the
offspring of relatively rich families who could more easily afford a child tax
(even though it would be higher in absolute terms), offering a better start in
life in terms of wealth and education. Although such a child tax is sure to
meet ethical and political resistance, one should recognize its unique capacity
to simultaneously address climate, overpopulation and long-term poverty
challenges. Moreover, the associated tax revenues could be used to reduce
existing income taxes so as to limit the overall tax burden for households
which might simultaneously increase employment (Freire-González, 2018).
Incidentally, an alternative for a child tax with similar consequences would be
a system of tradable birth permits (a combination of regulation and market
mechanism), as proposed by Boulding (1964) and elaborated by Daly (1977) and
others (see references in De La Croix and Gosseries, 2009).
6. A transition to an agrowth paradigm
One cannot be optimistic about
changing the current growth paradigm, but it is worth trying as the permanent
focus of our society and politicians on GDP growth forms a barrier to urgently
needed sustainability policies. The fear that stringent climate policies will
frustrate future economic growth is an important reason for many voters and
politicians to be reluctant to genuinely support such policies. This partly
explains why the Copenhagen climate summit failed and the recent Paris
agreement was designed around voluntary national climate targets rather than
globally harmonized policies. The discussion about climate versus growth will
probably intensify in the coming years now that the time available to limit
global warming is shrinking and serious emissions reductions are still awaited.
The literature on
growth-versus-climate shows that theoretical and empirical support for both
green growth and anti-growth is weak. Both strategies are risky and do not
provide sufficient guarantee for managing climate change or other
sustainability challenges. These strategies are also incompatible with a focus
on social welfare in normative micro and macroeconomic theories. A third,
neutral or indifferent vision called agrowth is more reasonable. It will create
a broader basis of support for stringent climate policies as it will
de-polarize the growth debate by bridging the opposition between green growth
and anti-growth positions. In contrast to pro-growth, the agrowth strategy does
not give priority to income growth over the climate, but is aimed at finding a
genuine balance between all aspects of social welfare. That is why it will
provide more political scope for effective climate policy, as well as for a
fair income distribution. In response to uncertainty about whether to be
optimistic or pessimistic about sustainable growth, one can follow a
precautionary strategy by being agnostic and being resilient to all possible
options.
Since the unconditional
pro-growth strategy is dogmatic in nature, change to a new agrowth paradigm
will be difficult. Current politics is characterized by nervous reactions to
low GDP growth. The preoccupation with GDP growth is invigorated by repetition,
in both education and the media, of the erroneous idea that growth is necessary
or even sufficient to solve important social problems. Higher economic growth
has also been shown to increases the likelihood that government leaders will
stay on longer (Burke, 2012). Hence, the pressure on politicians to be guided
by unconditional economic growth is unfortunately still great. If change does
occur, it is likely to come in stages, such as: first social sciences, then
economics, then politics and then voters.
Notes
[1] Aimed
at establishing neoclassical microeconomic foundations for macroeconomic
analysis.
References
Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P.,
Bursztyn, L. and Hemous, D., 2012. The environment and directed technical
change. American Economic Review102(1):
131-166.
Antal, M., and van den Bergh,
J.C.J.M., 2013. Macroeconomics, financial crisis and the environment: Strategies
for a sustainability transition. Environmental Innovation and
Societal Transitions 6:
47-66.
Antal, M., and van den Bergh,
J.C.J.M., 2016. Green growth and climate change: Conceptual and empirical
considerations. Climate Policy,
16(2): 165-177.
Arrow, K.J., Bolin, B.,
Costanza, R. Dasgupta,, P., Folke, C., Holling, C. S., Jansson, B.-O., Levin,
S., Mäler, K.-G., Perrings, C. and Pimentel, D., 1995. Economic growth,
carrying capacity, and the environment. Science 268(April 28): 520-21.
Bohn, H., and Stuart, C. 2015.
Calculation of a population externality. American Economic Journal:
Economic Policy 7(2):
61–87.
Bongaarts, J. and O’Neill,
B.C., 2018. Global warming policy: Is population left out in the cold? Science 361(6403):
650-652.
Boulding, K. E., 1964. The meaning of the twentieth century.
London: Allen & Unwin, Ltd.
Burke, P., 2012. Economic
growth and political survival. The B.E. Journal of
Macroeconomics 12(1):
1-43.
Chesnais, J.-C., 1992. The demographic transition: Stages, patterns, and economic
implications. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Daly, H.E., 1977. Steady-state economics: The political economy of biophysical
equilibrium and moral growth. San
Francisco: W.H. Freeman.
Daly, H.E., and Cobb, W., 1989, For the common good: redirecting the economy toward community, the
environment and a sustainable future. Boston: Beacon Press.
de la Croix, D., and Gosseries,
A., 2009. Population policy through tradable procreation entitlements. International Economic Review 50(2): 507–542
Drews, S., and Antal, M., 2016.
Degrowth: A “missile word” that backfires? Ecological Economics 126: 182-187.
Drews, S., and van den Bergh,
J.C.J.M., 2016. Public views on economic growth, the environment and
prosperity: Results of a questionnaire survey. Global Environmental Change 39: 1-14.
Drews, S. and van den Bergh,
J.C.J.M., 2017. Scientists’ views on economic growth versus the environment: a
questionnaire survey among economists and non-economists. Global Environmental Change 46, 88-103.
Easterlin, R.A., 1974. Does
economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David
and M. W. Reder, eds. 2014, Nations and households in
economic growth: Essays in honour of Moses Abramowitz. New York: Academic Press.
Felder, S., and Rutherford,
T.F., 1993. Unilateral CO2 reductions and carbon leakage: The
consequences of international trade in oil and basic materials. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 25: 162-176.
Frank, R.H., 2004. Positional
externalities cause large and preventable welfare losses. American Economic Review 95(2): 137-141.
Freire-González, J., 2018.
Environmental taxation and the double dividend hypothesis in CGE modelling
literature: A critical review. Journal of Policy Modeling 40(1): 194-223.
Galbraith, J.K., 1958. The affluent society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin
Company.
Gordon, R.J., 2012. Is U.S. economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the
six headwinds. [pdf] NBER Working Paper No. 18315. Available at: <http://www.nber.org/papers/w18315>
[Accessed 1 August 2018].
Harford, J. D., 1998. The
ultimate externality. American Economic Review88(1):
260–265.
Hirsch, F., 1976. Social limits to growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Hueting, R., 1974. Nieuwe schaarste and economische groei.
Amsterdam: Elsevier. (English edition 1980, New scarcity and economic
growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland. ).
Jackson, T., 2009, Prosperity without growth—economics for a finite planet.
London: Earthscan.
Jackson, T., and Victor, P.,
2011. Productivity and work in the ‘green economy’. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 1: 101-108.
Kahneman, D., Krueger, A.,
Schkade, D., Schwarz, N. and Stone, A., 2004. Toward national well-being
accounts. American Economic Review,
Papers and Proceedings 94:
429-434.
Kallis, G., 2011. In defence of
degrowth. Ecological Economics 70(5): 873-880.
Kennedy, J., 1995 Changes in
optimal pollution taxes as population increases. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 28(1): 19–23.
Kuznets, S., 1941. National income and its composition 1919–1938. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Layard, R., 2005. Happiness: Lessons from a new science.
London: Penguin.
Mishan, E.J., 1967. The cost of’ economic growth. London: Staples Press.
Nordhaus, W. D. and Tobin, J.,
1972. Is growth obsolete? In: Economic Growth.
New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, General Series No. 96. pp.1-80.
OECD, 2011. Towards Green Growth. Paris: OECD.
Pissarides, C.A.. 2000. Equilibrium unemployment theory (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Saget, C., 2000. Can the level
of employment be explained by GDP growth in transition countries? Theory versus
the quality of data. Labour 14(4): 623-643.
Samuelson, P.A., 1961. The
evaluation of social income: capital formation and wealth. In: F. Lutz and D.
Hague, eds. 1961, The Theory of Capital. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Schneider, F., G. Kallis and
Martinez-Alier, J., 2010. Crisis or opportunity? Economic degrowth for social
equity and ecological sustainability. Journal of Cleaner Production 18(6): 511-518.
Scitovsky, T., 1976. The joyless economy. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Sen, A., 1976. Real national
income. Review of Economic Studies 43(1): 19-39.
Sorrell, S., 2007. The rebound effect: an assessment of the evidence for economy-wide
energy savings from improved energy efficiency.
[pdf] UK Energy Research Centre. Available at:
<http://www.ukerc.ac.uk/Downloads/PDF/07/0710ReboundEffect> [Accessed 1
August 2018].
Tinbergen, J., and Hueting, R.,
1992. GNP and market prices: wrong signals for sustainable economic success
that mask environmental destruction. In: R. Goodland, H. Daly and S. El Serafy,
eds. 1992. Population, Technology and
Lifestyle: The Transition to Sustainability.Washington D.C.: Island Press.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., and de
Mooij, R.A., 1999. An assessment of the growth debate. In: J.C.J.M. van den
Bergh, ed. 1999. Handbook of Environmental and
Resource Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 643-655.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., and
Drews, S., 2019. Green “agrowth” – the next development stage of rich
countries. In Roger Fouquet ed. 2018. Handbook on Green Growth.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar (forthcoming).
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2009.
The GDP Paradox. Journal of Economic Psychology 30(2): 117-135.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2011.
Environment versus growth – A criticism of “degrowth” and a plea for
“a-growth”? Ecological Economics 70(5): 881-890.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2017a.
A third option for climate policy within potential limits to growth. Nature Climate Change, 7 (February),
107–12.
van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., 2017b.
Green Agrowth: Removing the GDP-growth constraint on human progress. Chapter 9
in: P.A. Victor and B. Dolter (eds.), Handbook on Growth and Sustainability.
Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 181-210.
Victor, P.A., 2008. Managing without growth. Slower by design, not disaster.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Weitzman, M.L., 1976. On the
welfare significance of national product in a dynamic economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 90: 156-162.
World Bank, 2012. Inclusive Green Growth – The Pathway to Sustainable Development.
Washington D.C.: The World Bank.
Wynes, S., and Nicholas, K.A.,
2017. The climate mitigation gap. Environmental Research Letters 12(7), 074024.