Achieving a post-growth green economy
First online: 25 November 2020
Douglas
E. Booth
Associate
Professor Retired, Marquette University
cominggoodboom@gmail.com
–––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––
DOI: 10.3197/jps.2020.5.1.57
Licensing: This article is Open Access (CC BY 4.0).
How to Cite:
Booth, D.E. 2016. 'Achieving a post-growth green economy'. The Journal of Population and Sustainability 5(1): 57–75.
https://doi.org/10.3197/jps.2020.5.1.57
–––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––
A transformation in human
values in a ‘post-materialist’ direction by middle-class youth around the world
may be setting the stage for a new reality of near-zero economic growth and a
sustainable and healthy global biosphere. Evidence from the World Values Survey
suggests that a global expansion of post-material values and experiences leads
to (1) a reduction in consumption-oriented activities, (2) a shift to more
environmentally friendly forms of life that include living at higher, more
energy efficient urban densities, and (3) active political support for
environmental improvement. Such behavioral shifts provide a foundation for a
turn to a slow-growth or even no-growth economy in comparatively affluent
countries to the benefit of a healthier global biosphere. To set the stage for
a ‘post-growth green economy’ that features climate stability and a
substantially reduced ecological footprint, the timing is right for a ‘Green
New Deal’ that focuses on de-carbonizing the global economy and has the
side-benefit of fostering an economic recovery from the Covid-19 global
recession currently underway. The financing of global decarbonization by the
world’s wealthiest countries is affordable and could stimulate much needed
economic improvements in developing countries by creating within them modern,
efficient clean energy systems that can serve as a basis for increased economic
prosperity. Such prosperity will in turn accelerate declines in population
fertility and result ultimately in reduced global population growth.
Keywords: post-materialism; post-growth economy;
green economy; population growth; sustainability.
Introduction
In
this day and age of existential threats to global social and economic
tranquility from the likes of climate change, rising economic inequality,
emerging authoritarian populism, and, now, a Covid-19 pandemic, to think about
prospects for the future may seem naïve. But the future will come and hope
springs eternal. Potentially, Covid-19 will teach us that global problems,
climate change in particular, cannot be ignored and that new approaches are
needed to arrive at a more just and environmentally friendly world. The purpose
of this article will be to suggest a possible path forward by thinking
seriously about interconnections between two phenomena: the ‘post-material
silent revolution’ as a key historical event; and a ‘post-growth green economy’
as a solution to the global environmental crisis. The central thesis offered
here is that these phenomena blend together comfortably as a framework for
thinking about our economic and environmental future.
The
‘post-material silent revolution’ amounts to a sea-change in values among
middle-class youth around the world away from giving high social priorities to
materialist, economic social goals and towards non-economic social purposes
such as advancing freedom of expression and increasing social tolerance. This
change is accompanied by less emphasis on the pursuit of wealth and material
possessions and more emphasis on seeking cultural and social experiences that
take place outside the sphere of economic transactions or within the economic
arena but for non-economic purposes. We will see that such a shift in outlook
and activity brings forth a less entropic and more environmentally friendly way
of living and greater political support for sustaining a healthy natural
environment that together may well lead to big changes in the way we think
about the economy.
A
‘post-growth economy’ refers here to the empirical phenomena of affluent
economies experiencing a slowing of growth in both per-capita incomes and
population as they mature and attain a threshold of material affluence.
Post-growth is achieved when those economies attain a no-growth status, or even
slow decline. Japan in recent years comes close to this status with a 0.8%
annual growth in GDP per capita (2000-2018) and 0.0% annual population growth
(World Bank, 2019c, 2019e).
Worried
about serious degradation of the earth’s natural environment by an
ever-expanding global economy, ecological economists have begun to consider the
somewhat heretical idea of a ‘post-growth economy’ as essential for halting the
over-exploitation of the biosphere caused by the excessive extraction of energy
and material resources, damaging emissions of waste materials and gases, and
the degrading and destruction of natural habitats. The post-growth idea is
heretical simply because continuous global economic growth is taken as a given
in the modern corporate-capitalist reality and as a fundamental requirement for
bringing the good life to all the peoples of the world. The necessity of
economic growth for living well and the compatibility of growth with a
sustainable global biosphere has been challenged by a number of authors,
challenges nicely summarized a few years ago in Peter Victor’s, Managing Without Growth and more recently by Tim Jackson’s Prosperity Without Growth (Jackson, 2017; Victor, 2008
pp.170-174). Simply put, no growth in the world’s highly developed countries is
essential to halting dangerous degradations of the earth’s environment, and a
post-growth economy is perfectly compatible with a decent life once a certain
threshold of prosperity is achieved. Other than for committed
environmentalists, a post-growth economy never has had a substantial political
constituency in the past, but with the emergence of increasing numbers of
post-materialists around the world, the absence of such a constituency is no
longer the case. Post-materialism provides a real-world value-foundation and
form of life for a materially and environmentally stable, ‘post-growth green
economy’. This
is the key proposition to be explored in the pages to follow.
The post-material silent
revolution
The
future spreading of a post-material silent revolution around the world, I will
now argue, provides an economic and political foundation for a post-growth
green economy, an outcome that may well be essential to prevent the existential
threat of climate change to the global biosphere (more on this in the next
section). The silent revolution will assist in bringing about such an economy
for the following reasons: (1) first and foremost, post-materialists likely
consume relatively less over their life-time than materialists with similar
economic opportunities; (2) post-material forms of living and experiences tend
to be less entropic than materialist ways of life; and most important of all
(3) post-materialists are more supportive of environmental protection than
others in both their attitudes and political actions.
Post-materialists
are individuals whose quest in life has shifted away from the acquisition of
material possessions and towards the pursuit social goals and experiences
valued for their own sake largely outside the realm of market transactions
(Booth, 2018a). This quest is enabled by having grown up in social environments
of reasonable physical and material security that permit a lifetime focus on
higher ordered purposes at the upper reaches of the hierarchy of human needs
(Inglehart, 1971; Maslow, 1987). Such individuals are less interested than
others in gaining riches and material possessions and achieving publicly
recognized personal success according to analyses of World Values Survey, Wave
6 (2010-2014) data covering 60 countries and more than 85,000 respondents
worldwide (Booth, 2018a; World Values Survey Association, 2015).
Post-materialists also possess a universalist outlook meaning they desire to
take positive actions to the benefit of society as a whole and for the
protection of nature and the earth’s environment. Adding this all up infers
that post-materialists are prone to consume less in the way of material
possessions over their lifetime than others with similar economic
opportunities. Thus, the silent revolution in post-material values likely
serves to dampen life-time consumption and the material throughput that goes
with it.
Having
attained a basic threshold of economic security and material possessions,
post-materialists not only limit their overall demand for material goods, but
as a matter of taste seek a comparatively low-entropy, form of life placing
less demand on energy and materials flows to the benefit of the environment.
Post-materialists are more inclined than others to reside in larger, denser
cities that are more energy efficient and thus less entropic than the
spread-out suburban areas so attractive to their older peers after World War II
(Booth, 2018b). Energy efficiency increases with human density for such reasons
as reduced human travel distances; less use of energy inefficient private motor
vehicles and more use of energy efficient public transit; and lower per person
consumption of private dwelling space and associated heating and cooling energy
requirements (New York City, 2007; Newman & Kenworthy, 1999, 2015).
In the USA a return to downtown living has been driven in part by Millennials
choosing to live in high-density urban neighborhoods as opposed to spread out
low-density suburbs (Birch, 2005, 2009). Even in already densely populated
countries such as Germany, center-city, dense neighborhoods recently
experienced a relative surge in population growth driven by younger generations
(Brombach, Jessen, Siedentop, & Zakrzewski, 2017). Complementary to
higher-density living by younger generations in the USA, the rate of car
ownership and the miles of driving undertaken by Millennials is less than their
older peers (Polzin, Chu, & Godrey, 2014). Higher urban densities support
more of the publicly shared experience opportunities afforded by parks,
libraries, public squares, museums, art galleries, entertainment and sports
venues, spaces for group meetings and public demonstrations, street cafes, and
more that provide opportunities for a post-material mode of living (Markusen,
2006; Markusen & Gadwa, 2010; Markusen & Schrock, 2006).
In
addition to being oriented to a less entropic form of life, post-materialists
exhibit greater support for the environment than others in terms of both their
attitudes and actions in the world (Booth, 2017; Inglehart, 1995). This support
is not just a matter of personal preferences but includes such overt actions as
contributing to environmental groups, attending environmental protests, and in
Europe giving support to the Green Party movement.
To
summarize, the long-term trend to post-materialism around the world fueled by
generational replacement is a good thing for the global biosphere by fostering
more energy efficient, less entropic forms of living, taking the pressure off
of growing demand for material possessions that threatens the global biosphere,
and increasing active political support for protecting the global
biosphere. This trend lends support to the emergence of a ‘post-growth
green economy’ as a foundation for stabilizing the global climate in particular
and increasing the health of the biosphere in general.
The post-growth green economy
The
concept of a post-growth green economy is inspired by the recognition that a
global economic system functioning within a fixed biosphere cannot expand
forever without doing substantial harm to the latter (Daly, 1991, 2018). The
biosphere receives energy but only miniscule amounts of materials from the
solar system of which it is a part. The economic system is totally
dependent on the biosphere for both energy and matter. The laws of
thermodynamics tell us that, while neither energy nor matter can be destroyed,
their quality declines with human use. The economic system extracts high
quality energy and materials from the biosphere and returns waste heat and
low-quality waste materials back to it. The supply of energy and matter is
ultimately limited as is the capacity of the biosphere to absorb resulting
wastes without undue harm to biotic functioning. Accounting for this
limitation, a post-growth green economy is founded on the principle that energy
and materials flows in particular, and the environmental scale of the economy
in general, should be capped at sustainable amounts consistent with an
ecologically healthy biosphere (Booth, 1998).
Paradoxically,
the problem with a post-growth green economy is not so much attaining zero
growth but realizing a green economy such that energy and material flows and
waste emissions are capped at sustainable levels consistent with the
maintenance of global ecosystem health. The next section will focus on bringing
waste emissions down to environmentally sustainable levels within the context
of a post-growth economy, and the current section will address the seeming
inevitability of realizing a post-growth economy.
For
those countries at the upper-end of the human development hierarchy, the notion
of a zero-growth economy is quickly coming to fruition. If we look at the
world’s high-income countries, their population fertility rate has already
reached 1.6 children per female and their annual population growth rate is down
to 0.64% per year and will eventually turn negative (Table 1). For the most
affluent countries of the world, zero population growth or even population
decline will be a fact of life in the not too distant future assuming an
absence of a significant upsurge in immigration. Moreover, for this same group
of countries, real GDP growth per capita is slowing as well and is down to 1.2%
a year between 2000 and 2018 from 2.4% between 1980 and 2000, a 50% drop (World
Bank, 2019c). With zero or even negative population growth and with the GDP
annual growth rate per capita closing in on 1% or less, a no-growth economy
looks to be on the way for the world’s most affluent countries.
This
prospect leaves us with important unresolved questions: Why are the wealthiest
economies in the world tending towards zero economic growth? Is this a problem
for human well-being in wealthy countries? In a world where many countries need
human development and expansion of their economies to achieve a minimum
threshold income necessary for the good life, is there a path to forestalling
excessive climate change by mid-century and ultimately attaining sufficient
economic security for all the world’s citizens that would enable a global
post-growth green economy?
Growth
in constant dollars GDP divides into two factors: (1) growth in population, and
(2) growth in real GDP per capita. Growth in population ultimately depends on
the fertility rate, the number of births per female, of which the population
replacement level is approximately 2.1. Over the long-run, fertility rates
above this number result in population growth and below it in population
shrinkage. Fertility rates appear to be heavily dependent on the level of human
and economic development. Basically, as material affluence increases, fertility
diminishes as shown in the data in Table 1. Approximately half the world’s
population (High Income plus Upper Middle Income, Table 1) now possesses a
fertility rate below replacement levels at approximately 1.81 and the other
half (Lower Middle Income plus Low Income, Table 1) has a fertility of approximately
3.0. With global fertility at 2.4, long-run population stability is within
reach. By roughly doubling the GDP per capita for the lower half of the world’s
population, their fertility rate can probably be driven below 2.1. Doing so
would result in an average GDP per capita for the lower half at least equal to
the GDP per capita of the upper-middle income ($8,537) countries who currently
possess a fertility rate of 1.9, which is below the population replacement
level (Table 1). At the current GDP per capita growth rate for the lower half,
a more than doubling of GDP per capita will occur in less than 30 years.
As
shown by Table 1 data, in both high-income and OECD countries, GDP per capita
is growing at a historically modest rate just above 1% annually. Such growth
theoretically occurs from a combination of increases in the number of hours
worked per capita and in output per hour worked (constant $ GDP/hours worked).
Between 2000 and 2018, OECD hours worked per capita remained unchanged, while
output per hour (labor productivity) has grown 1.2% annually (OECD, 2019a,
2019b, 2019c). Growth in GDP per capita is consequently due entirely to
productivity growth, but at a rate that over the long run has been in decline
for wealthy countries. As Tim Jackson notes, labor productivity in the world’s
most advanced economies has fallen steadily from a high in the 4% range just
after World War II to around 2% in the 1980s and 1990s, and now to less than 1%
since the turn of the century. As he also notes, the reasons for this are a
matter of some contention and include a slowing in the pace of technological
innovation placing a drag on the supply side of the economy and stagnant growth
on the demand side of the economy dampening productivity improving investment
in new production facilities (Jackson, 2017 pp. 43-46). Slower growth on the
demand side of the economy is driven in part by growing economic inequality, a
lack of real wage growth, and the disruptions of the 2008-2009 Great
Recession (Alvaredo, Chancel, Piketty, Saez, & Zucman, 2017; Saez, 2009;
Stiglitz, 2010; Wisman, 2013). A shift in the structure of modern
post-industrial economy in the direction of services and away from goods can
make a difference as well. Face-to-face human services intrinsically lack
opportunities for labor productivity improvements, meaning that overall
productivity growth is likely to shrink as the service sector expands
relatively (Jackson, 2017, 170-174). In addition, since many service jobs are
low-paying, a relative expansion of services can place a drag on earnings at
the lower end of the social class structure (Storm, 2017) adding to economic
inequality. These reasons for slower growth in productivity imply that modern
capitalism possesses critical inner flaws that taken together will ultimately
bring economic growth as we know it to an end.
A
slowing of growth in the world’s most affluent economies could also be occurring
for positive reasons below the radar as a matter of public choice, and not
entirely as the result of dis-functional economic arrangements. The
post-material silent revolution described above amounts to a turning away from
the pursuit of more material possessions to other purposes once a threshold of
material security is achieved. For the total World Values Survey, Wave 6
sample, 31% of the respondents selected a majority of post-material social
options for the questions behind the construction of the Inglehart
post-materialism index instead of economically focused materialist options
(Booth, 2018a; World Values Survey Association, 2015). This number rises to
39.8% for affluent countries in the top 25% of the human development hierarchy
as measured by the Human Development Index (United Nations Human Development
Program, 2018). A substantial proportion of the population in wealthy countries
subscribes to post-materialist social goals, and many of those same individuals
participate in post-materialist experiences outside the arena of market
transactions. Engaging in such experiences likely dampens consumer spending and
could well lead to a slowdown in aggregate demand growth and in economic
expansion. The point is a simple one; achieving a decent and satisfying life is
contingent on a minimum threshold of material wealth but ‘not’ on continuous
economic growth once that minimum is achieved.
This
is exactly the same point made by both Jackson and Victor in their separate
works on no-growth economics (Jackson, 2017; Victor, 2008). Both note that
neither happiness nor genuine social progress necessarily occurs as a
consequence of GDP growth. Happiness does increase with income up to a certain
minimum, but after that the rate of increase flattens out. A minimum
country-level GDP per capita threshold is required to achieve relatively high
life expectancy and a decent education, both essential to
life-satisfaction. Beyond this threshold, post-materialists shift gears
towards supporting non-economic social goals such as freedom of
self-expression, having more say in all of life’s arenas, and supporting a more
humane society based on ideas rather than money. Post-materialism around the
world bears a strong positive correlation to such basic values as being creative
and doing something for the good of society and the environment (Booth, 2018a).
Those who engage in post-materialist experiences desire connections with others
in voluntary organizations, creative and independent activity in their work,
and active political participation in the pursuit of valued social goals. These
are ‘intrinsic’ purposes, as opposed to materialist ‘extrinsic’ ends sought in
market transactions, and bear a strong relationship to the intrinsic values
of “self-acceptance, affiliation, and a sense of belonging in the
community” mentioned by Jackson as important for flourishing in a prosperous
world where economic growth ceases to be a fundamental social premise (Jackson,
2017). In support of a basic human desire for realizing intrinsic values,
Jackson points to a ‘quiet revolution’ of people accepting lower incomes to
leave room in life for the simple pleasures (reading, gardening, walking,
listening to music), getting involved in the voluntary simplicity movement,
or taking part in creative and engaging activities characterized by a sense of
flow (a state of heightened focus). These are exactly the kinds purposes sought
by those possessing post-material values and engaging in post-material
experiences, phenomena that find substantial empirical support in the World
Values Survey (Booth, 2018a, 2018b).
To
sum up, the world’s richest countries are tending towards annual rates of
economic expansion in per capita income below 1% and annual rates of population
growth likely to fall below zero in the not too distant future absent
significant immigration. Potential explanations for the decline in per capita
income growth include a mix of structural problems on both the demand and
supply side of the economy. Alternatively, the decline may not be a problem at
all but simply reflect a movement by a portion of the population beyond
extrinsic materialist pursuits in life to more satisfying post-materialist
intrinsic purposes. Future population declines follow from fertility
rates below replacement levels that have in turn resulted from relatively high
rates of affluence and human development.
Climate change and achieving a
green global economy
An
essential environmental virtue of a post-growth economic system is the stabilizing
of the extraction of energy and materials from, and waste emissions into, the
global biosphere. A post-growth economic system has other environmental
benefits as well including limitations on the human damage to ecosystem
functioning required for both human and nonhuman species survival. Such
stability in energy and materials throughputs and ecological harms doesn’t
necessarily mean a healthy and sustainable biosphere since existing (stable)
rates of human environmental intrusions may well lead to continuing ecological
degradation. In other words, certain human-caused environmental harms will have
to be reduced below existing levels for a healthy and sustainable biosphere in
a post-growth economy. A simple steady state in the human use of the environment
will not be enough. The Global Footprint Network, for example, reports
that the worldwide ecological footprint in terms of hectares of land needed to
supply the world with the 2016 volume of ecological resources consumed on a
sustainable basis is approximately 1.7 times the amount of land available
globally. In brief, this rate of consumption is above the sustainable level,
and the earth’s resources will continue to degrade under steady-state
consumption at the 2016 rate (Global Footprint Network, 2020). For future
reference, note that if the global economy were 80% decarbonized as will be
describe below, then worldwide ecological footprint would decline to
approximately 0.9 times the amount of land available based on the 2016 numbers.
Decarbonization would in effect eliminate the huge land requirements for carbon
absorption and bring the ecological footprint into sustainability.
The
most threatening of all human induced environmental harms clearly is the
unsustainability of waste greenhouse gases being emitted into the global
atmosphere. Even in a global no-growth economy, such emissions would continue
at climate threatening rates, although these would slowly diminish over time
because of improvements in energy efficiency and resulting reductions in CO2 emissions
per unit of global GDP (currently approximately 0.6% per year) (Jackson, 2017
p.97). Currently, worldwide CO2 emissions stand at around 36 billion
metric tons annually (Table 1). To drive these emissions down by 80% at
mid-century over a thirty-year period would require an annual rate of decline
of approximately 5.2%. Without any concerted action to cut emissions further, no-growth
global economy emissions would only decline by about 20% over 30 years to 29
billion at a 0.6% annual rate. In brief, a no-growth economy globally would not
be enough to come anywhere near de-carbonizing the economic system as a whole.
A global no-growth economy would be a help, but it is not the final solution to
the existential threat of a warming global climate. In a no growth economy, a
4.6% (5.2 -0.6) annual reduction in emissions will be needed for 80%
decarbonization in 30 years. This is indeed less than required in a
‘normal-growth’ global economy with GDP per capita projected to expand over the
next 30 years at a rate of around 1.3% per year and population projected to
grow at 0.8% per year (Jackson, 2017, p. 97). In this case the annual percent
decline in emissions would need to be 6.7% per year (5.2-0.6+1.3+0.8) to
achieve 80% decarbonization.
While
there is nothing new or unfamiliar in the Table 1 statistics, a number of
interesting messages can be gleaned from them. First, as just noted, if current
trends continue the world’s high-income countries are on track to be ‘no-growth
economies’ with GDP per capita income growth trending towards zero and
population growth moving into negative territory. Second, population fertility
remains above the magic 2.1 stabilization rate for roughly the poorest half of
the world’s countries, and an annual GDP per capita above $8,500 apparently
results in fertility dropping below this number. Simply put, per capita income
growth of 2% per year or more over the next 30 years for the poorest half of
the world’s population appears to be a feasible route to bringing fertility
down to population stabilizing levels. Because of the age structure of
populations in low income countries, actually reaching population stability
will take time and could be accelerated with a greater current commitment to
family planning efforts (Sachs, 2008). Growth in per capita income for the
poorest half would also be a help in getting to a basic economic security
threshold capable of bringing on a shift to the pursuit of post-material values
and experiences as opposed to further acquisitions of material possessions.
Third, an 80% decarbonization of the global economy in the next 30 years
appears to be a relative bargain, costing a bit more than 1% of global GDP per
year. Setting China aside as capable of paying its own way, high-income
countries could finance 80% decarbonization for the entire world (excluding
China) at a cost of roughly 1.3% of their GDP per year for 30 years.[1]
The
term ‘Green New Deal’ originated in the UK with a proposal to tackle the 2008
‘Great Recession’ with a large-scale program of public investments and economic
reforms to expand employment, reduce economic inequality, and to create a clean
energy sector for the purpose of bringing climate change to heel (Green New
Deal Group, 2008). More recently, in reaction to the Trump administration’s
attack on USA environmental regulations and with the return of the Democratic
Party to power in the House of Representatives in 2018, a Green New Deal
resolution with similar purposes passed the House (U.S. House of
Representatives, 2019). While the global economic future after the Covid-19
pandemic at this point is murky, the global economy will most likely enter an
economic recession or even a depression with a dramatic decline in economic
activity as a result of business shutdowns to bring spreading of the virus
under control. To foster an economic recovery will surly require an
unprecedented global economic stimulus of which investment in clean energy and
other forms of decarbonization could be quite popular given that a second
crisis in the form of climate change and its devastating consequences will be
staring at everyone on the horizon. The beauty of a Green New Deal is its
probable high degree of political acceptability. It gives environmentalists and
post-materialists a project around which they can coalesce and gain political
momentum; it will create large numbers of well-paying working-class jobs and
potentially bring working-class disaffected populists on board weaning them
away from a currently emergent anti-environment authoritarian populism (Norris
& Inglehart, 2019) in the process; and, last but not least, such a project
could bring the majority of global business interests (fossil fuels excepted)
on board by causing the global economy to flourish with a boom that creates a
new clean energy sector and brings about economic recovery. The process of
replacing fossil fuel with clean energy will create jobs on two counts: First,
clean energy alternatives such as solar and wind will be more labor intensive
than the fossil fuels they are replacing, meaning that employment in the energy
sector will permanently increase as a result of the shift; and secondly, the
initial investment in clean energy facilities will mean a temporary boom in
employment and a surge in economic growth lasting over the transition period
(Garrett-Peltier, 2017; Wei, Patadia, & Kammen, 2010).
My
primary purpose here is to comment on the possible role of a Green New Deal in
setting the stage for a stable and healthy global biosphere. Others have done a
good job in describing how Green New Deal decarbonization can be implemented
(Heal, 2017; Sachs, 2019). First and foremost, a global decarbonization project
could set us on track for climate stabilization at an affordable cost, one that
could easily be fully borne by the world’s high-income countries, setting them
back about 1.3% of their annual GDP as noted above. The financing of a global
Green New Deal by high-income countries would have to be coordinated globally,
perhaps through the Green Climate Fund established by the Paris Climate Accord
(Green Climate Fund, 2019). An obvious virtue of such an approach to financing
would be to foster greater economic equity at a global level between rich and
poor as well as gaining support for decarbonization from all low and
middle-income countries.
Second,
in a Covid-19 economic recovery, debt-financed expenditures on decarbonization
will help high income countries get back to their original levels of economic
activity and also foster economic expansion in the world’s middle and
low-income economies.[2] The
recovery of high-income economies will be advanced by producing much of the
world’s clean energy equipment, and the middle and low-income economies will be
boosted by not only the work of installing such equipment, but by the creation
of a modern energy sector that for many countries did not previously exist and
can serve as a point of departure for other development projects. For the
world’s developing countries, decarbonization and a global Green New Deal can
help push per capita GDP towards thresholds necessary to bring about zero
population growth and provide enough economic security to make a ‘post-material
silent revolution’ globally feasible.
Conclusion
The
essential hypothesis here is this: The ‘post-material silent revolution’,
enabled by the attainment of a critical level of material and physical security
that permits lives less-focused on further economic achievements, sets the
stage for a ‘post-growth economy’ that ultimately can bring the global economic
system into a sustainable balance with the global biosphere. Currently, this is
just a hypothesis, but one that is consistent with a shift by a significant
share of the global population beyond an emphasis on materialist to
post-materialist values and modes of life. This hypothesis is also consistent
with, but not necessarily the entire cause of, a reduction in economic growth
rates to 1% or less for many of the world’s most affluent economies.
Paradoxically, a Green New Deal is proposed here that will actually stimulate
worldwide economic growth in the short-run and at the same time put humanity on
a path to bring a halt to the existential threat of climate change. Such a
stimulus will help foster recovery of the global economy from the Covid-19
economic downturn and set developing economies on a path to reasonable material
security for all of humanity. More importantly, if 80% global decarbonization
had already occurred, the ecological footprint as measured in 2016 would
actually have been about .9 rather than 1.7 due to the reduction in
requirements for carbon absorption, bringing the footprint into sustainability.
Whatever the level of the ecological footprint turns out to be in 2050, it will
be substantially less than otherwise because of decarbonization. In brief,
short-run green economic growth is needed to set the stage for a green
post-growth economy consistent with a stable and healthy global biosphere. Hope
does spring eternal.
Notes
[1]The
decarbonization cost estimates are based on numbers for the USA in (Heal,
2017). Heal estimates 30-year decarbonization costs to fall in a best-case to
worse-case range from $1.3 trillion to $4 trillion. Using the
worst-worst-case figure this equals about $952 per mt for 4.2 million mt USA
emissions reduction over 30 years, or about $32 per ton annually. These cost
figures are likely to be similar to those faced by other high-income economies.
Costs are likely to be somewhat less for countries with lower wage rates such
as China. China is included in the World Bank, Upper Middle-Income country
category, but that country possesses a sophisticated clean energy equipment
industry already and can likely afford to achieve decarbonization using its own
resources. China is already a major exporter of solar panels and other clean
energy equipment and will thus benefit substantially from a global
decarbonization effort. Looking at the cost estimate as a percentage of the
current year GDP means that the annual cost in absolute terms will increase
annually by the growth rate of GDP more than accounting for GDP related
possible growth in emissions.
[2]To
finance the Green New Deal,
high-income countries would be advised to issue long-term government backed
debt-obligations to avoid the drag on economic recovery that tax-financed
spending would bring. Once recovery has occurred, then debt-obligations could
be slowly retired, perhaps funded by a small ‘automated payment transactions’
tax that would be progressive and at the same time would dampen overall
financial transactions and thus contribute to sustaining a ‘post-growth
economy’ (Feige, 2000). Such a tax would likely have a mild negative effect on
consumer expenditures but could well diminish the volume of financial
transactions significantly, especially those undertaken for speculative
purposes. Since the bulk of payment transactions are undertaken in association
with financial assets disproportionately held by the wealthy, the
redistributive effects of payments transactions tax would probably be
progressive.
Alvaredo,
F., Chancel, L., Piketty, T., Saez, E., and Zucman, G. 2017. Global inequality
dynamics: new findings from The World Wealth and Income Database. American Economic Review, 107(5), pp.404-409.
Birch,
E. L., 2005. Who lIves downtown? In A. Berube, B. Katz, and R. E. Lang, eds.
2005. Redefining urban and suburban
America: evidence from Census 2000. Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution
Press. pp.29-49.
Birch,
E. L., 2009. Downtown in the “new American city”. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science,
626(1), pp.134-153.
Booth,
D. E. 1998. The environmental consequences
of growth: steady-state economics as an alternative to environmental decline.
London: Routledge.
Booth,
D. E. 2018a. Postmaterial experience economics. Journal of Human Values, 24(2), pp.1-18.
Booth,
D. E. 2018b. Postmaterial experience economics, population, and environmental
sustainability. Journal of Population and
Sustainability, 2(2), pp.33-50.
Brombach,
K., Jessen, J., Siedentop, S., and Zakrzewski, P., 2017. Demographic patterns
of reurbanisation and housing in metropolitan regions in the U.S. and Germany. Comparative Population Studies, 42, pp.281-317.
Daly,
H., 2018. Envisioning a successful steady-state economy. Journal of Population and Sustainability,
3(1), pp.21-33.
Daly,
H. 1991. Steady-state economics 2nd ed. Washington D.C.: Island Press.
Feige,
E. L., 2000. Taxation for the 21st century: The automated payment transaction
(APT) tax. Economic Policy,
15(31), pp.473-511.
Garrett-Peltier,
H., 2017. Green versus brown: comparing the employment impacts of energy
efficiency, renewable energy, and fossil fuels using an input-output model. Economic Modelling, 61, pp.439-447.
Green
Climate Fund, 2019. Achieving the Paris Agreement:
How GCF raises climate ambition and empowers action.
[online] Available at: https://www.greenclimate.fund/document/achieving-paris-agreement-how-gcf-raises-climate-ambition-and-empowers-action#
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
Global
Footprint Network, 2020. Data and methodology: World
ecological footprint by land type. [online] Available at:
https://www.footprintnetwork.org/resources/data/ [Accessed 27 October 2020].
Green
New Deal Group, 2008. A
green new deal. [pdf]
Available at:
https://neweconomics.org/uploads/files/8f737ea195fe56db2f_xbm6ihwb1.pdf
[Accessed 27 October 2020]
Heal,
G., 2017. What would It take to reduce U.S. greenhouse gas emissions 80 percent
by 2050? Review of Environmental
Economics and Policy, 11(2), pp.319-335.
Jackson,
T., 2017. Prosperity without growth:
foundations for the economy of tomorrow 2nd ed. London: Routledge.
Markusen,
A., 2006. Urban development and the politics of a creative class: evidence from
a study of artists. Environment and Planning, 38,
pp.1921-1940.
Markusen,
A., and Gadwa, A., 2010. Arts and culture in urban or regional planning: a review
and research agenda. Journal of Planning Education
and Research, 29(3), pp.379-391.
Markusen,
A., and Schrock, G., 2006. The artistic dividend: Urban artistic specialisation
and economic development implications. Urban Studies,
43(10), pp.1661-1686.
New
York City, 2007. Inventory of New York City
greenhouse gas emissions. [pdf] Available at:
http://www.nyc.gov/html/planyc/downloads/pdf/publications/greenhousegas_2007.pdf
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
Newman,
P., and Kenworthy, J. R. 1999. Sustainability and cities:
overcoming automobile dependency. Washington D.C.: Island
Press.
Newman,
P., and Kenworthy, J. R., 2015. The end of automobile
dependence: how cities are moving beyond car-based planning.
Washington D.C.: Island Press.
Norris,
P., and Inglehart, R., 2019. Cultural backlash: Trump,
Brexit, and authoritarian populism. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
OECD,
2019a. Hours worked.
[online] Available at: https://data.oecd.org/emp/hours-worked.htm [Accessed 27
October 2020].
OECD,
2019b. Level of GDP per capita and
productivity. [online]
Available at: https://data.oecd.org/lprdty/gdp-per-hour-worked.htm
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
OECD,
2019c. Labour force participation
rate. [online]
Available at: https://data.oecd.org/emp/labour-force-participation-rate.htm
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
Polzin,
S. E., Chu, X., and Godrey, J., 2014. The impact of Millennials’ travel
behavior on future personal vehicle travel. Energy Strategy Reviews, 5, pp.59-65.
Sachs,
J., 2008. Common wealth: economics for a
crowded planet. New
York: Penguin Press.
Sachs,
J., 2019. Getting to a carbon-free
economy. [online]
Available at:
https://prospect.org/greennewdeal/getting-to-a-carbon-free-economy/ [Accessed
27 October 2020].
Saez,
E., 2009. Striking it richer: the evolution of top incomes in the United States
(update with 2007 estimates). UC Berkeley: Institute for
Research on Labor and Employment. [online]
Available at: https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8dp1f91x [Accessed November 4, 2020].
Stiglitz,
J. E., 2010. Freefall: America, free
markets, and the sinking of the world economy. New
York: W.W. Norton.
Storm,
S., 2017. The new normal: demand, secular stagnation, and the vanishing middle
class. International Journal of
Political Economy, 46(4), pp.169-210.
U.S.
House of Representatives, 116th Congress, 2019. House Resolution 109. Recognizing the duty of the federal
government to create a green new deal.Washington D.C.: U.S.
Government Printing Office.
Victor,
P. A., 2008. Managing without growth: slower
by design, not disaster. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
Wei,
M., Patadia, S., and Kammen, D. M., 2010. Putting renewables and energy
efficiency to work: how many jobs can the clean energy industry generate in the
U.S.? Energy Policy, 38,
pp.919-931.
Wisman,
J. D., 2013. Wage Stagnation, rising inequality and the Financial Crisis of
2008. Cambridge Journal of Economics,
37(4), pp.921-945.
World
Bank, 2019a. CO2 emissions (kt).
[online] Available at:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/EN.ATM.CO2E.KT?end=2014&start=1960&view=chart
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
World
Bank, 2019b. Fertility rate, total (births
per woman). [online] Available at:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.DYN.TFRT.IN/ [Accessed 27 October
2020].
World
Bank, 2019c. GDP per capita (constant 2010
US$). [online] Available at: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.KD
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
World
Bank, 2019d. Population growth (annual %).
[online] Available at:
http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.POP.GROW?end=2011&start=1961
[Accessed 27 October 2020].
World
Bank, 2019e. Population, total. [online] Available at:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/sp.pop.totl [Accessed 27 October 2020].